Showing posts with label Journal of Libertarian Studies. Show all posts
Showing posts with label Journal of Libertarian Studies. Show all posts

Sunday, April 18, 2021

Philosophically, Friedmanism Would Destroy Money Itself and Reduce Us to the Chaos and Primitivism of the Barter System

There is no question about the fact that the present international monetary system is an irrational and abortive monstrosity, and needs drastic reform. But Friedman’s proposed reform, of cutting all ties with gold, would make matters far worse, for it would leave everyone at the complete mercy of his own fiat-issuing state. We need to move precisely in the opposite direction: to an international gold standard that would restore commodity money everywhere and get all the money-manipulating states off the backs of the peoples of the world. 

Furthermore, gold, or some other commodity, is vital for providing an international money—a basic money in which all nations can trade and settle their accounts. The philosophical absurdity of the Friedmanite plan of each government providing its own fiat money, cut loose from all others, can be seen clearly if we consider what would happen if every region, every province, every state, nay every borough, county, town village, block, house, or individual would issue its own money, and we then had, as Friedman envisions, freely fluctuating exchange rates between all these millions of currencies. The ensuing chaos would stem from the destruction of the very concept of money—the entity that serves as a general medium for all exchanges on the market. Philosophically, Friedmanism would destroy money itself, and reduce us to the chaos and primitivism of the barter system. 

One of Friedman’s crucial errors in his plan of turning all monetary power over to the State is that he fails to understand that this scheme would be inherently inflationary. For the State would then have in its complete power the issuance of as great a supply of money as it desired. Friedman’s advice to restrict this power to an expansion of 3–4% per year ignores the crucial fact that any group, coming into the possession of the absolute power to “print money,” will tend to . . . print it!

 —Murray N. Rothbard, “Milton Friedman Unraveled,” Journal of Libertarian Studies 16, no. 4 (Fall 2002): 50.


Saturday, April 17, 2021

“The Business Cycle Largely a ‘Dance of the Dollar’” (1923) Set the Model for the “Purely Monetary” Theory of the Business Cycle

In keeping with this outlook, Irving Fisher wrote a famous article in 1923, “The Business Cycle Largely a ‘Dance of the Dollar’”—recently cited favorably by Friedman—which set the model for the Chicagoite “purely monetary” theory of the business cycle. In this simplistic view, the business cycle is supposed to be merely a “dance,” in other words, an essentially random and causally unconnected series of ups and downs in the “price level.” The business cycle, in short, is random and needless variations in the aggregate level of prices. Therefore, since the free market gives rise to this random “dance,” the cure for the business cycle is for the government to take measures to stabilize the price level, to keep that level constant. This became the aim of the Chicago School of the 1930s, and remains Milton Friedman’s goal as well. 

Why is a stable price level supposed to be an ethical idea, to be attained even by the use of governmental coercion? The Friedmanites simply take the goal as self-evident and scarcely in need of reasoned argument. But Fisher’s original groundwork was a total misunderstanding of the nature of money, and of the names of various currency units. In reality, as most nineteenth century economists knew full well, these names (dollar, pound, franc, etc.) were not somehow realities in themselves, but were simply names for units of weight of gold or silver. It was these commodities, arising in the free market, that were the genuine moneys; the names, and the paper money and bank money, were simply claims for payment in gold or silver. But Irving Fisher refused to recognize the true nature of money, or the proper function of the gold standard, or the name of a currency as a unit of weight in gold. Inst4ead, he held these names of paper money substitutes issued by the various governments to be absolute, to be money. The function of this “money” was to “measure” values. Therefore, Fisher deemed it necessary to keep the purchasing power of currency, or the price level, constant. 

This quixotic goal of a stable price level contrasts with the nineteenth-century economic view—and with the subsequent Austrian School. They hailed the results of the unhampered market, of laissez faire capitalism, in invariably bringing about a steadily falling price level. For without the intervention of government, productivity and the supply of goods tends always to increase, causing a decline in prices. Thus, in the first half of the nineteenth century—the “Industrial Revolution”—prices tended to fall steadily, thus raising the real wage rates even without an increase of wages in money terms. We can see this steady price decline bringing the benefits of higher living standards to all consumers, in such examples as TV sets falling from $2000 when first put on the market to about $100 for a far better set. And this in a period of galloping inflation. 

—Murray N. Rothbard, “Milton Friedman Unraveled,” Journal of Libertarian Studies 16, no. 4 (Fall 2002): 46-47.


The Key Problem with Friedman’s Fisherine Approach Is the Same Orthodox Separation of the Micro and Macro Spheres

The third major feature of the New Deal program was proto-Keynesian: the planning of the “macro” sphere by the government in order to iron out the business cycle. In his approach to the entire area of money and the business cycle—an area on which unfortunately Friedman has concentrated most of his efforts—Friedman harks back not only to the Chicagoans, but, like them, to Yale economist Irving Fisher, who was the Establishment economist from the 1900s through the 1920s. Friedman, indeed, has openly hailed Fisher as the “greatest economist of the twentieth century,” and when one reads Friedman’s writings, one often gets the impression of reading Fisher all over again, dressed up, of course, in a good deal more mathematical and statistical mumbo-jumbo. Economists and the press, for example, have been hailing Friedman’s recent “discovery” that interest rates tend to rise as prices rise, adding an inflation premium to keep the “real” rate of interest the same; this ignores the fact that Fisher had pointed this out at the turn of the twentieth century. 

But the key problem with Friedman’s Fisherine approach is the same orthodox separation of the micro and macro spheres that played havoc with his views on taxation. For Fisher believed, again, that on the one hand there is a world of individual prices determined by supply and demand, but on the other hand there is an aggregate “price level” determined by the supply of money and its velocity of turnover, and never the twain do meet. The aggregate, macro, sphere is supposed to be the fit subject of government planning and manipulation, again supposedly without affecting or interfering with the micro area of individual prices.

—Murray N. Rothbard, “Milton Friedman Unraveled,” Journal of Libertarian Studies 16, no. 4 (Fall 2002): 45-46.


Monday, March 22, 2021

The Two Rules Regulating Socialism’s Capital Structure Can Be Viewed Profitably Alongside their Free-Market Counterparts

The controversy surrounding socialism does not so much concern the above; rather, it concerns production and how socialism can have accurate factor pricing without competition. Lange here introduces several rules that are intended to replace and improve upon capitalist production. The first rule is to have all producers equalize the ratios of marginal productivity to their prices, for all the factors of production (e.g.,  MPa ÷ Pa = MPb ÷ Pb = MPn ÷ Pn ).

The second rule, to be used in tandem with the above, is to price production equal to marginal cost, a principle first recommended by Fred Taylor and readily adopted by Lange. This marginal cost principle, the welfare ideal of neoclassical economics, is addressed not only to the singular firms but to the industries as well.

The above two rules regulating socialism’s capital structure can be viewed profitably alongside their free-market counterparts. Profit maximization under capitalism is replaced by producing at minimum average cost. Free entry/exit and the optimum size of plant in the market order are likewise duplicated by the same rule. The second rule, of setting price to marginal cost, conforms to the “pure and perfect competition” ideal under capitalism. Setting marginal benefits to marginal costs is seen as maximizing welfare (the Pareto optimality) for society. In all, the rules fully cover the economics of production, “determin[ing] the combination of factors of production and the scale of output” while also maximizing welfare. 

—Robert Bradley Jr., “Market Socialism: A Subjectivist Evaluation,” Journal of Libertarian Studies 5, no. 1 (Winter 1981): 24-25.