Showing posts with label What’s Wrong with Keynesian Economic Theory?. Show all posts
Showing posts with label What’s Wrong with Keynesian Economic Theory?. Show all posts

Saturday, July 11, 2020

For Frank Knight, John Maynard Keynes Succeeded in Carrying Economic Thinking Well Back to the Dark Age

The Keynesian avalanche soon swept away virtually all the competing approaches, ideas, or theories with which to explain the business cycle. Indeed, there was hardly a voice in the mainstream of the economics profession that was willing or able to directly question or challenge the near Keynesian monopolization of economic thinking on problems of economy-wide fluctuations in employment, output, and prices.

When Frank H. Knight declared in his 1951 presidential address before the American Economic Association that in his view “The latest ‘new economics’ and in my opinion rather the worst, for fallacious doctrine and pernicious consequences, is that launched by the late John Maynard (Lord) Keynes, who for a decade succeeded in carrying economic thinking well back to the dark age” (Knight, 1951, p. 2) it must have created shock and disbelief among many who heard these words spoken. Few besides Frank Knight could have been so blunt without permanently risking their reputation and standing in the economics profession of that time.

What was this “dark age” back to which Keynes took economic thinking? At its core, I would suggest, was its focus on macroeconomic aggregate building blocks: Aggregate Demand, Aggregate Supply, Total Output and Employment, and the average Price Level and Wage Level.

—Richard M. Ebeling, “The Misdirection of Keynesian Aggregates for Understanding Monetary and Cyclical Processes,” in What’s Wrong with Keynesian Economic Theory? ed. Steven Kates (Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, 2016), 79.


Sunday, March 15, 2020

Few Saw the 2007-08 Crisis Coming Because Most DSGE Models Exclude Key Variables Like Loose Credit

Since the mid-1950s, macroeconomic theorizing evolved from what has been aptly called ‘hydraulic Keynesianism’ into dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models of the economy. In the process, this type of theorizing has come to dominate mainstream economics, absorbing both Keynesians and neoclassicals within the same methodological paradigm. Neoclassicals insist that changes in monetary conditions can have no effect on real outcomes, whereas Keynesians invoke ‘price stickiness’ and other rigidities to come to different conclusions.

Despite longstanding and convincing objections to the DSGE model, on the eve of the financial crisis of 2007–08 it commanded almost universal support within the mainstream of the economics profession. The unquestioning nature of this support has been compared by Roger Koppl to John Stuart Mill’s endorsement of the cost-of-production theory of value shortly before its overturning by the marginalist revolution in the last quarter of the nineteenth century.

The credibility of mainstream macroeconomic thinking has been fatally undermined, not yet by an alternative theory but by its inability to explain either the proximate or the underlying causes of the crisis of 2007–08. Nor has it been able to offer any explanation for the unexpected duration of the subsequent recession. It is widely acknowledged that the proximate cause of the financial crisis was a loss of confidence on the part of some major financial intermediaries in the ability of counterparties to meet their obligations. Hence the ‘credit crunch’ by which this loss of confidence was transmitted to the real economy.

The more fundamental origins of the crisis are to be found in the loose credit and regulatory policies that were pursued in earlier years, permitting an unsustainable boom in house and other asset prices. Neither of these factors appears among the list of variables specified in most DSGE models, so it is not surprising that few academics or policymakers ‘saw the crisis coming’.

—David Simpson, “What’s Wrong with Keynesian Economics?” in What’s Wrong with Keynesian Economic Theory? ed. Steven Kates (Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing, 2016), 203.